• You will need to login or register before you can post a message. If you already have an Agriville account login by clicking the login icon on the top right corner of the page. If you are a new user you will need to Register.

Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

CWB PROs

Collapse
X
Collapse
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

    #11
    Liberty and charliep.
    The DPC tracks minneapolis DNS fairly closely as far a I know. How DPC prices are arrived at I am not exactly sure although I did hear the explanation but it is better if it comes from someone at the CWB who knows for sure.

    Liberty, your point "by comparing PNW port prices over the period of a crop year with the CWB's total payment, after adjusting for the value of the Can$. My study is not exhaustive, but thus far I've found that the CWB pooled price was about the same as for PNW ports in around two months of the crop year (2005). The rest of the time it varied up to a dollar a bushel less on our side of the border. Where are the premiums for Canadian producers? I'm not even finding them at port position."

    And charlieP, "I can also phone a maltster and find out prices they are paying the CWB pooling system for malt barley. They are likely (haven't checked lately) at least a buck bushel higher than the current malt barley PRO. Where does the money go?"

    My answer to both these points is essentialy the same whether it is malt barley or CWRS. The pooled price will reflect sales to North American markets and all the other markets we sell to. Since some of those sales will be at lower values than what we can get in North America the pool return will reflect the average weighted value. When you try to compare North American spot market prices, or the DPC price to pool returns, you are comparing only one market to the pool return results from the average of many markets. That is not to say the CWB is not selling into the North American markets at the higher value you are seing in ND or at the Canadian maltsers. But these values can be diluted with sales at lower values in other markets such as China, Indonesia, and Colombia. North America, the EU, and Japan are higher value markets but we cannot sell our entire crop to these markets so our overal pool return prices is going to be lower most of the time. The $1 dollar difference between Canadian Malt prices and the current pool price for malt barley is not lost. The CWB will be capturing that price and putting it into the pool account for each grade and quality.

    Richard Gray et al.have just released a study on the CWB and barley from 1994 - 2004. I only heard a few details on the news this AM so I need to see the study. What Gray said on the Radio is that the CWB's single desk premium for malt barley is worth about $60 million a year or about $1.00 per bsuhel. He also said that the benefits of the CWB on feed barley are harder to determine and much lower or nonexistant because most of the feed barley grown here does not go through the CWB. In effect the feed barley market is a dual market and probably illustrates the difficulty of being effective in a dual market situation.

    When we debate this issue about whether the CWB is of benefit or not we need to realize that there is alot more complexity to this than first meets the eye. Simple comparisons of prices do not tell the whole story. I don't have all the answers so I think we have rely on those best qualified to do the analysis and then make our own minds up based on the best information possible.

    Comment


      #12
      A farmer can believe studies or they can look at prices. That is their choice. I will highlight the issues raised in the study noted on the WBGA website.

      Comment


        #13
        chuckChuck

        Since you are particating here, I hope you can help all of us (including me) understand the law of one price. It would seem to indicate farmers are not able to differentiate markets based on consumers needs/wants, quality characturistics and supply/logistics commitment. I note that farmers already do this for oats, peas, specialty oil canola, organic crops. What makes malt barley different?

        Comment


          #14
          In most years lately the Malt price has just barely beat the domestic feed price where I live.

          If the CWB is doing such a great job and getting $1 more per bushel, then no one would grow malt barley if the CWB was gone, because it would consistently be lower than feed barley price. I seriously doubt this would happen, and therefore conclude that there is no premium of $1 per bushel being gained.

          Comment


            #15
            THE CANADIAN WHEAT BOARD
            AND
            BARLEY MARKETING Gray et al 2005
            EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
            The operation of the CWB as the singledesk
            seller of Western Canada’s feedbarley
            and malting barley for export and
            for domestic human consumption within
            Canada is at the centre of ongoing
            debate and controversy in Western
            Canada. Some key issues raised are:
            1) Does the CWB deliver higher returns
            to Western Canada’s feed-barley and
            malting-barley producers than would
            be the case in a multiple-seller
            environment?
            2) Are there benefits provided to
            producers through the price-pooling
            operations of the CWB (i.e., risk
            management)?
            3) What are the inherent problems of
            arbitrage between the annual pooled
            return (APR) provided by the CWB
            and the cash off-Board market price?
            4) Are there additional marketing costs
            that are unique to the operation of
            the CWB as a single-desk seller?
            • Recent studies that have examined
            the economic issues surrounding
            barley marketing in Western Canada
            and North America have focused
            primarily on feed barley, with less
            emphasis on malting barley. Thus the
            lack of focus on the interrelationship
            between these two different barley
            markets has limited the usefulness of
            many earlier studies when
            determining the implications of
            various possible marketing
            arrangements for barley producers,
            the livestock industry, and the
            malting industry. In addition, these
            studies have major data limitations
            because they have had little or no
            access to actual CWB sales prices
            and contract terms.
            • The specific objectives of this study
            are:
            1) To provide an overview of the world
            barley trade for both malting and
            feed barley (Section II);
            2) To review previous studies
            examining the role of the CWB in
            the domestic and international barley
            market (Section III);
            3) To develop a theoretical framework
            to examine the role of the CWB in
            domestic and international feedbarley,
            barley-malt, and maltingbarley
            markets, and the potential for
            the CWB and other market
            participants to exercise market power
            (Section IV);
            4) To test whether the CWB exhibits
            market power in the international
            feed-barley market when utilizing
            actual CWB contract data for the
            1995/96 to 2003/04 crop years
            (Section V);
            5) To estimate the returns from a
            single-desk-seller marketing system
            using an economic model that uses
            actual CWB sales transaction data
            (Section V);
            6) To review and evaluate the
            additional marketing costs found in
            previous studies that have been
            attributed to the CWB (Section VI);
            7) Discuss price variability in the
            Canadian and U.S. barley markets;
            8) To discuss barley marketing in a
            highly volatile market setting; and
            9) To provide a summary and
            conclusion of the analysis (Section
            VIII).
            • World barley production has dropped
            sharply since the 1980s. The largest
            decrease has been in the production
            of feed barley. Historically, the
            ii
            largest barley producer has been the
            European Union. The major barley
            exporters are the European Union,
            Australia, the Ukraine, and Canada.
            Trade in malting barley has
            accounted for roughly 30% of world
            barley trade. Since 1994/95, world
            malting-barley trade has increased by
            roughly 45%. The major maltingbarley
            exporters are the European
            Union, Australia, and Canada but the
            European Union, Russia, and the
            Ukraine dominate the feed-barley
            export market. The European Union
            is by far the largest barley-malt
            exporter, followed by Canada, which
            exports primarily malt and malting
            barley. The largest importers of
            malting-barley from Canada are
            China and the United States. Most
            feed-barley produced in Canada is
            used as feed domestically and is not
            marketed through the CWB. World
            barley markets are influenced highly
            by political interventions and by
            agricultural policy.
            • Earlier work pointed out that the
            CWB has been able to price
            discriminate among markets
            (Schmitz et al. 1997). The average
            difference between CWB contract
            prices for Japan and the United
            States over the 1980/81 through
            1994/95 period was significant and
            averaged $25.29/mt. The difference
            between CWB contract prices for the
            U.S. and ROW markets was also
            significant, with an average price
            difference of $4.46/mt. The
            difference between CWB contract
            prices to Japan and the ROW
            markets was significant and averaged
            $20.73/mt.
            • In this study, data were used from
            every CWB sale of feed barley, 6-
            row malting barley, and 2-row
            malting barley for the 1995/96 to
            2003/04 crop years. The data were
            compiled from CWB contract
            records. All prices were brought to a
            common basis point of either FOB
            Vancouver or St. Lawrence. The
            sales data were aggregated into the
            following nine market segments: 1)
            Japan’s feed-barley market; 2) U.S.
            feed-barley market; 3) all other feedbarley
            markets; 4) Canada’s
            domestic 6-row malting-barley
            market; 5) U.S. 6-row malting-barley
            market; 6) offshore 6-row maltingbarley
            markets; 7) Canada’s
            domestic 2-row malting-barley
            market; 8) U.S. 2-row malting-barley
            market; and 9) offshore 2-row
            malting-barley markets. In the
            analysis, the CWB allocates the total
            quantity of barley it receives from
            producers in a given crop year across
            the above 9 markets in such a way as
            to maximize total sales revenue. In
            order to measure the impact that
            multiple sellers of Canada’s feed
            barley and malting barley would
            have had on returns and trade flows,
            a comparison was made between the
            actual market structure (i.e., prices
            and quantities) observed under the
            CWB and the prices and quantities
            that would have existed if there had
            been multiple sellers of Canada’s
            feed barley and malting barley.
            The key difference between the
            CWB system and a multiple-seller
            system is the ability to price
            discriminate. In the absence of
            constraints on the quantity of feed
            barley, 6-row malting barley, and 2-
            row malting barley available for sale
            iii
            by Canada’s producers, the law of
            one price must hold for all
            international and domestic barley
            sales in a multiple-seller
            environment. In the model used,
            multiple sellers were assumed to be
            fully competitive, and this
            competition resulted in one market
            price for feed barley and one market
            price for malting barley at any point
            in time, which is a characteristic of
            all competitive markets.
            • The impact on prices and revenue of
            replacing the CWB with multiple
            sellers of feed barley, 6-row malting
            barley, and 2-row malting barley for
            each year from 1995/96 through
            2003/04 are as follows:
            1) The annual average price increase
            earned by the CWB for 6-row
            malting barley relative to what a
            multiple-seller marketing structure
            would have had from 1995/96 to
            2003/04 was $35.25/mt. This number
            was computed as the simple average
            of the difference in the weightedaverage
            price of 6-row malting
            barley under the CWB versus what
            the equilibrium price of 6-row
            malting barley would have generated
            under the multiple-seller model. For
            example, the 2000/01 price
            difference was $43.19/mt, which is
            equal to the difference between the
            weighted-average price of 6-row
            malting barley under the CWB and
            the weighted-average price of 6-row
            malting barley under a multiple
            seller scenario. Relative to multiple
            sellers, the CWB is estimated to have
            captured higher prices on sales of 6-
            row malting barley in all years
            except 1995/96.
            2) The calculated annual average price
            difference between what the CWB
            received and what a multiple-seller
            structure would have received on
            sales of 2-row malting barley for the
            1995/96 to 2003/04 crop years is
            $40.29/mt. Relative to multiple
            sellers, the CWB is estimated to have
            captured higher prices in 2-row
            malting-barley markets in every year
            considered here. Under the CWB,
            the lowest price premium for 2-row
            malting barley was $19.64/mt in
            2003/04 and the highest price
            premium was $61.82 in 2002/03.
            3) The impact on producer revenue
            from replacing the CWB with
            multiple sellers of Canada’s barley is
            large. For example, the introduction
            of multiple sellers of Canada’s feed
            barley and malting barley in 2000/01
            would have caused Canada’s barley
            producers to lose $128 million in
            total revenue. Over the 1995/96
            through 2003/04 period, the
            introduction of multiple sellers
            would have resulted in an annual
            average loss of $59 million in
            revenue accruing to Canada’s barley
            producers. Multiple sellers of
            Canada’s barley would have caused
            losses in revenue to Canada’s barley
            producers in every year considered
            here.
            • Results were derived using different
            values for the price elasticity of
            demand for Canada’s feed barley in
            the rest of the world (ROW) and the
            price elasticity of domestic demand
            for Canada’s feed barley. Under
            these alternative assumptions over
            the 1995/96 to 2003/04 crop years,
            the introduction of a multiple-seller
            marketing system would have
            iv
            resulted in an annual average loss of
            between $36 million and $58 million
            in revenue accruing to Canada’s
            barley producers. Also, results were
            obtained in which the malting barley
            selection rate under a multiple-seller
            marketing system was constrained.
            Under restricted malting barley
            selection rates over the 1995/96 to
            2003/04 crop years, the introduction
            of a multiple-seller marketing system
            would have resulted in an annual
            average loss of between $17 million
            and $28 million in revenue accruing
            to Canada’s barley producers.
            • The impact of replacing the CWB
            with multiple sellers of Canada’s
            barley was estimated by Schmitz et
            al. (1997) for the 1985/86 to 1994/95
            crop years. On average, the revenue
            accruing to producers of Canada’s
            barley would have been reduced by
            $72 million per year under multiple
            sellers of Canada’s barley. This
            number is higher than the $58
            million per year estimated for the
            1995/96 to 2003/04 crop years in this
            study. There are at least three major
            reasons for the differences between
            the two studies. First, Canada was a
            significant net importer of feed
            grains (barley and corn combined) in
            several years over the 1995/96 to
            2003/04 crop years (especially
            2001/02 and 2002/03) whereas
            Canada was not a net importer of
            feed grains over the 1985/86 to
            1994/95 period. Second, there are
            several years over the 1995/96
            through 2003/04 period in which the
            ROW feed-barley-export market was
            not the lowest priced market; this
            was not the case for the 1985/86
            through 1994/95 period. This could
            have implications for the results due
            to the fact that the price elasticity of
            demand for Canada’s feed-barley
            exports to the ROW is set at a
            relatively high level (i.e., –20.0
            associated with the base results).
            Third, the CWB’s ability to attain
            price premiums increased in the
            presence of the Export Enhancement
            Program (EEP), which was
            terminated in the late 1990s.
            • Some authors argue that the singledesk-
            seller marketing system has
            larger system costs than does a
            multiple-seller marketing system.
            While most of the costs identified are
            present in Canada’s system, they are
            not unique to CWB grain marketing.
            Most, if not all, of the costs that
            earlier studies identified would have
            been incurred in the absence of the
            CWB as a single-desk-seller
            marketing system and likely in the
            same order of magnitude. The CWB
            currently uses an annual pooled
            return to distribute sales revenue to
            producers. This mechanism does not
            provide a signal to producers that
            fully responds on a timely basis to
            changing market conditions within a
            given crop year. If export market
            prices change substantially during a
            crop year, the prevailing pooled
            return will not reflect this change on
            a timely basis. This creates some
            economic losses because the export
            value of feed barley at a given point
            in time is not fully reflected by the
            CWB pool return outlook (PRO) and
            by the cash off-Board market price in
            the domestic feed-barley market in
            Western Canada. A situation in
            which export feed-barley prices rise
            during the crop year and the PRO
            does not increase as rapidly, more
            barley is used as feed in Western
            v
            Canada than would result under a
            multiple seller marketing system
            without price pooling. This creates
            an economic loss. A loss also results
            when export barley prices fall during
            a crop year and the PRO does not fall
            as rapidly. In this situation, the PRO
            and Canada’s domestic feed-barley
            prices are above the prevailing world
            price. As a result, less feed barley is
            fed domestically and feed-barley
            exports to the world market are
            larger than would otherwise occur.
            Recent changes instigated by the
            CWB as price signals to farmers,
            such as cash off-Board market
            pricing and two shorter pooling
            periods, are expected to reduce the
            issue of incomplete arbitrage.
            • To analyze barley price variability,
            an earlier study compared Lethbridge
            AB off-Board feed-barley prices to
            U.S. feed-barley-prices at Great Falls
            MT and Devil’s Lake ND as well as
            to other U.S. points. The average
            annual standard deviation in the
            Lethbridge AB cash off-Board
            market price for the 1988/89 to
            1995/96 crop years was $7.88/mt.
            The average September cash off-
            Board market price in Lethbridge
            AB was on average $7.88/mt above
            or below the average price for the
            crop year. This compares to $7.88/mt
            and $7.23/mt measured at Great Falls
            MT and Devil’s Lake ND,
            respectively. However, from 1999 to
            2003 feed-grain price variability was
            slightly higher for Lethbridge AB
            than it was for Great Falls MT.
            However, barley prices were
            consistently higher in Lethbridge AB
            than in Great Falls MT.
            • The single-desk-seller marketing
            system of barley creates more sales
            revenue for Western Canada’s
            farmers than would be the case under
            a multiple-seller marketing system
            due to the ability of the CWB to
            exercise market power. The
            magnitude of the additional revenue
            created varies by year depending
            upon factors that include the
            occurrence and degree of export
            subsidization in feed-barley and
            malting-barley markets. The benefits
            of the CWB single-desk-seller
            marketing system are largest for
            malting barley.
            • Feed-barley prices from 1999 to
            2003 are consistently higher for
            Lethbridge, AB than for Great Falls
            MT by an average of roughly
            $20/mt. Second, during the drought
            period of 2002, there was significant
            variability in barley prices, but this
            was clearly reflected in the CWB
            malting-barley-price forecasts.
            Imports of malting barley that year
            were due largely to shortages in
            malting barley in Canada. Because of
            the 2002 drought, Canada also
            imported large quantities of corn
            from the United States to make up
            for the shortage of feed barley. As a
            result, it is difficult to argue that
            barley markets are not arbitraged.
            • There have been many studies
            conducted on the CWB in the
            marketing of barley that support the
            notion that the CWB can price
            discriminate in international markets
            and, hence, can earn price premiums
            above what a multiple seller of
            Canada’s barley would earn. Results
            consistent with those presented in
            this report were used in at least two
            legal cases involving the CWB– the
            Charter Case and the U.S.
            Countervail Beef Case against
            Canada. In both cases, allegations
            that the CWB was highly inefficient
            in barley marketing could not be
            supported.
            • When analyzing the international
            barley market we emphasize that it is
            ever changing especially the feedbarley
            markets where Canada’s
            exports have decreased along with
            CWB sales of domestic feed barley
            within Canada. In addition, over the
            last several years, barley producers
            in Canada have not been subsidized
            through the CWB as there has been
            no deficit in the barley pool and
            government credit guarantees on
            sales have been negligible. Also, at
            least since 2000, Canada’s feedbarley
            prices have been consistently
            higher than those in the United
            States.

            Comment


              #16
              ChuckChuck;

              THis is a laugh.

              "The key difference between the
              CWB system and a multiple-seller
              system is the ability to price
              discriminate. In the absence of
              constraints on the quantity of feed
              barley, 6-row malting barley, and 2-
              row malting barley available for sale
              iii
              by Canada’s producers,

              the law of
              one price must hold for all
              international and domestic barley
              sales in a multiple-seller
              environment.

              In the model used,
              multiple sellers were assumed to be
              fully competitive, and this
              competition resulted in one market
              price for feed barley and one market
              price for malting barley at any point
              in time, which is a characteristic of
              all competitive markets."

              Talk to Monsanto. They sell their product at $10/L and $4/L. Now if that isn't price discrimination...

              And guess what... I paid both of these prices myself this year... and applied them to kill our weeds.

              Price Discrimination is normal in almost every business today, and the "law of
              one price" is the exception far more than the rule.

              I don't know if you saw this CHuckChuck...

              I think it might add a little perspective to the U of S view of the world!

              What determines a business success?

              Suppose that in 1972, someone had asked you to pick the five companies that would provide the greatest return to stockholders over the next 20 years. Conventional economic theory would be a guide, so how would you approach the assignment?

              In order to create prosperity, the companies we pick should have some sustainable competitive advantage, and something that:
              a) distinguishes this organization from others in the business;
              b) creates value for the industry it is involved in;
              c) provides a service that is not easily copied.

              Conservative economic strategy would have us pick the “right” industries as step one.
              The 5 strategies for fundamental success would be:
              i) difficult entry for new competitors;
              ii) a product or service that isn’t easily substituted;
              iii) low market power of the buyers;
              iv) low market power of the sellers; and
              v) cooperation between the competitors.
              Economies of scale, patent protection, (a monopoly) and the largest market share would help a good selection process.

              What would have been the best business strategy between 1972 and 1992? If we had taken conventional wisdom… and turned it on it’s head… we would have done the BEST!

              Here are the results, the top 5 stocks, in reverse order:

              Plenum Publishing, (15,689%)
              Circuit City, (16,410%)
              Tyson Foods, (18,118%)
              Walmart, (19,807%)
              Southwest Airlines, (21,775%)

              Yet; Airlines, Retailing, Food processing, and publishing industries were awash is bankruptcies and massive competition during this time period.

              Therefore… what made these five good businesses and what sustained their advantage?

              It was not market power, technology, patents, or strategic position…

              It was how they handled their work force.


              CHuckChuck... I think even you would have to admit the CWB has done a VERY poor job in handling it's work force... the grain growers of western Canada!

              Comment


                #17
                I will note the study makes very little reference between the domestic market and the CWB export market. In farmer terms today when they are given choice, they are able to review multiple price offers on any given day and select the highest price. The best example is feed barley - how much is sold to the export market? Under what condition are farmers are farmers willing to deliver? On the last point, the only major deliveries of feed barley to the export market have occurred when the CWB and one or more grain companies have cut deals to come up with effectively a daily cash price for export feed barley (or at least a price guarantee.

                On the malt side, there are really very limited markets the CWB sells too. Domestic maltsters, US and China. Why couldn't an open market sell equally as effectively to these markets as the CWB? What services does the CWB provide the malt market other than some market development and a gate keeper on price? The CWB is not involved in selection. They are not involved in sourcing. In most cases they are not involved in sales. What value (from a farmer perspective) do they bring to the table?

                Comment


                  #18
                  Who got the the plaque?


                  ---------------------------------------
                  ! 2006 CWB GOLD AWARD
                  ! singlicala-deskoretta
                  ! CUSTOM SPUN
                  ! REPORT SPECIALIST
                  ! CHAMPIONS
                  ---------------------------------------

                  Comment


                    #19
                    Someone do the math. Take the final payments from the last number of years and deduct the premiums the study says are accrued to the CWB. End result under this senario is no one would grow barley. If there is anything we can learn from all the studies done on the benefit or cost of the CWB is that there is biases on both sides of the issue to get the end result that is desired. In the end people will only believe the study they want to believe.

                    Comment

                    • Reply to this Thread
                    • Return to Topic List
                    Working...